Jump to content

Poisson games

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Large poisson game)

In game theory and political science, Poisson games are a class of games often used to model the behavior of large populations. One common application is determining the strategic behavior of voters with imperfect information about each others' preferences.[1] Poisson games are most often used to model strategic voting in large electorates with secret and simultaneous voting.

A Poisson game consists of a random population of players of various types, the size of which follow a Poisson distribution. This can occur when voters are not sure what the relative turnout of each party will be, or when they have imperfect polling information. For example, a model of the 1992 United States presidential election might include 4 types of voters: Democrats, Republicans, and two classes of Reform voters (those with second preferences of either Bill Clinton or George H.W. Bush).

Main assumptions[edit]

The first assumption of the model is that the total number of players of each type follows a Poisson distribution. In other words, the probability of voters turning out to support a given candidate is given by:

More important is the assumption that voters are only interested in securing the best possible election outcome for themselves, and are motivated only by the possibility of casting the deciding vote. In other words, voters are assumed not to care about expressing their true opinions; about showing support for a minor party, even if they do not win; or about allowing other voters' voices to be heard. All of these effects tend to produce more honest voting in real elections than would be found in the Poisson model.

In the model, all information is publicly-available, meaning that every voter can estimate the probability that each pair of candidates will be tied. An example of this would be an election with public opinion polling.

Results[edit]

The Poisson voting model generates several key results.

Approval and score[edit]

Under the Poisson model, approval voting and score voting behave identically, as each voter's best strategy involves casting a ballot that assigns every candidate either the maximum or minimum score.

The Nash equilibria (best strategies), of such voting systems are always weakly sincere. In other words, voters are incentivized to provide an honest ranking of the candidates (i.e. voters approve a candidate if and only if the candidate is above a certain quality threshold). This can be seen as "contradicting" the Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem, which is often mischaracterized as saying that every system rewards insincere voting.

In reality, there is no contradiction, for two reasons. First, the Gibbard–Satterthwaite theorem applies only to ranked-choice voting, whereas approval is a rated system. Second, while Gibbard's theorem shows cardinal systems cannot be perfectly honest either, it requires a much stronger idea of honesty: it shows no voting system has an honest (or dishonest) dominant strategy, i.e. one where the best vote does not depend on other voters' ballots or the popularity of the candidates at all.

Plurality[edit]

Under plurality, sincere voting is never a stable equilibrium, i.e. many voters are incentivized to lie about their favorite candidate and vote for the lesser of two evils. For example, in the 2016 United States presidential election, some polls suggest that Gary Johnson was the majority-preferred winner. However, Johnson ultimately received only a small fraction of the vote because voters expected him to lose, creating a self-fulfilling prophecy.[2]

Similar results can be found for instant-runoff voting, which in the three-candidate case also creates insincere equilibria and can fail to elect the most popular candidate.[citation needed]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ Myerson, Roger (1998). "Population Uncertainty and Poisson games". International Journal of Game Theory. 27 (27): 375–392. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.21.9555. doi:10.1007/s001820050079.
  2. ^ Potthoff, Richard F.; Munger, Michael C. (November 2021). "Condorcet Loser in 2016: Apparently Trump; Condorcet Winner: Not Clinton?". American Politics Research. 49 (6): 618–636. doi:10.1177/1532673X211009499. ISSN 1532-673X.