User:TheQuiteSide/sandbox

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

>

Under a gold standard, paper notes are convertible into pre-set, fixed quantities of gold.
Gold certificates were used as paper currency in the United States from 1882 to 1933. These certificates were freely convertible into gold coins.

The gold standard is a monetary system in which the standard economic unit of account is a fixed weight of gold. There are distinct types of "gold standards".

The gold specie standard is a system in which the monetary unit is associated with circulating gold coins, or with the unit of value defined in terms of one particular circulating gold coin in conjunction with subsidiary coinage made from a less valuable metal. Similarly, the gold exchange standard does not typically involve the circulation of gold coins. Rather, it uses notes or coins made of silver or other metals, but where the authorities guarantee a fixed exchange rate with another country that is on the gold standard. This creates a de facto gold standard, where the values of the notes and non-gold coins in circulation have fixed external values in terms of gold that is independent of their inherent values. The gold bullion standard is a system in which gold coins do not circulate, but the authorities have agreed to sell gold bullion on demand at a fixed price in exchange for circulating currency.

No country currently uses a gold standard as the basis of its monetary system, although several hold substantial gold reserves.

History[edit]

Beginnings[edit]

The gold specie standard was not designed, but rather arose out of a general acceptance that gold was useful as a universal currency.

[1]

When commodities compete for the role of money, the one that over time loses the least value takes on the role.[2] The use of gold as money dates back thousands of years.[3]

During the Middle Ages, the Byzantine gold Solidus, commonly known as the Bezant, circulated throughout Europe and the Mediterranean. However, as the Byzantine Empire's economic influence declined, Western Europe generally adopted a silver standard as part of the Carolingian reforms.[4]

Silver pennies, based on the Roman Denarius, became the staple coin of Britain around the time of King Offa, circa AD 796, and similar coins, including Italian denari, French deniers, and Spanish dineros circulated throughout Europe. Following the Spanish discovery of silver deposits at Potosí in Bolivia and in Mexico during the 16th century, international trade came to depend on coins such as the Spanish dollar, the Maria Theresa thaler, and, in the 1870s, the United States Trade dollar.

In modern times the British West Indies was one of the first regions to adopt a gold specie standard. Following Queen Anne's proclamation of 1704, the British West Indies gold standard was a de facto gold standard based on the Spanish gold doubloon coin. In the year 1717, the master of the Royal Mint Sir Isaac Newton established a new mint ratio between silver and gold that had the effect of driving silver out of circulation and putting Britain on a gold standard.

However, only in 1821, following the introduction of the gold sovereign coin by the new Royal Mint at Tower Hill in the year 1816, it was the United Kingdom who formally put on a gold specie standard, the first of the great industrial powers to do so. Soon to follow was Canada in 1853, Newfoundland in 1865, the USA and Germany de jure in 1873. The USA used the Eagle as its unit, and Germany introduced the new gold mark, while Canada adopted a dual system based on both the American Gold Eagle and the British Gold Sovereign.

Australia and New Zealand adopted the British gold standard, as did the British West Indies, while Newfoundland was the only British Empire territory to introduce its own gold coin as a standard. Royal Mint branches were established in Sydney, New South Wales, Melbourne, Victoria, and Perth, for the purpose of minting gold sovereigns from Australia's rich gold deposits.

The crisis of silver currency and bank notes (1750–1870)[edit]

In the late 18th century, wars within Europe as well as an ongoing trade deficit with China (which sold to Europe but had little use for European goods) drained silver from the economies of Western Europe and the United States. Coins were struck in smaller and smaller numbers, and there was a proliferation of bank and stock notes used as money.

United Kingdom[edit]

In the 1790s, the United Kingdom, suffering a massive shortage of silver coinage, ceased to mint larger silver coins and issued "token" silver coins and overstruck foreign coins. With the end of the Napoleonic Wars, the United Kingdom began the great recoinage programme that created standard gold sovereigns and circulating crowns and half-crowns, and eventually copper farthings in 1821. The recoinage of silver in United Kingdom after a long drought produced a burst of coins: the United Kingdom struck nearly 40 million shillings between 1816 and 1820, 17 million half crowns and 1.3 million silver crowns.

The 1819 Act for the Resumption of Cash Payments set 1823 as the date for resumption of convertibility, reached instead by 1821. Throughout the 1820s, small notes were issued by regional banks, which were finally restricted in 1826, while the Bank of England was allowed to set up regional branches. In 1833, however, Bank of England notes were made legal tender, and redemption by other banks was discouraged. In 1844 the Bank Charter Act established that Bank of England notes, fully backed by gold, became the legal standard. According to the strict interpretation of the gold standard, this 1844 act marks the establishment of a full gold standard for British money.

United States[edit]

The United States adopted a silver standard based on the Spanish milled dollar in 1785. This was codified in the 1792 Mint and Coinage Act, and by the Federal Government's use of the "Bank of the United States" to hold its reserves, as well as establish a fixed ratio of gold to the U.S. dollar. This was, in effect, a derivative silver standard, since the bank was not required to keep silver to back all of its currency.

This began a long series of attempts by the USA to create a bi-metallic standard for the U.S. Dollar, which would continue until the 1920s. Gold and silver coins were legal tender, including the Spanish real. Because of the huge debt taken on by the U.S. Federal Government to finance the Revolutionary War, silver coins struck by the government left circulation, and in 1806 President Jefferson suspended the minting of silver coins.

The U.S. Treasury was put on a strict hard-money standard, doing business only in gold or silver coin as part of the Independent Treasury Act of 1848, which legally separated the accounts of the Federal Government from the banking system. However, the fixed rate of gold to silver overvalued silver in relation to the demand for gold to trade or borrow from England. The drain of gold in favor of silver led to a search for gold, including the California Gold Rush of 1849. Following Gresham's law, silver poured into the USA, which traded with other silver nations, and gold moved out. In 1853, the USA reduced the silver weight of coins to keep them in circulation, and in 1857 removed legal tender status from foreign coinage.

In 1857 the final crisis of the free banking era of international finance began as American banks suspended payment in silver, rippling through the very young international financial system of central banks. In 1861 the U.S. government suspended payment in gold and silver, effectively ending the attempts to form a silver standard basis for the dollar.

International[edit]

Through the 1860–1871 period, various attempts to resurrect bi-metallic standards were made, including one based on the gold and silver franc; however, with the rapid influx of silver from new deposits, the expectation of scarcity of silver ended.

The interaction between central banking and currency basis formed the primary source of monetary instability during this period. The combination that produced economic stability was a restriction of supply of new notes, a government monopoly on the issuance of notes directly and, indirectly, a central bank and a single unit of value. Attempts to avoid these conditions produced periodic monetary crises.

As notes devalued, or silver ceased to circulate as a store of value, there was a depression. Governments, demanding specie as payment, drained the circulating medium out of the economy. At the same time, there was a dramatically expanded need for credit and large banks were being chartered in various states, including, by 1872, Japan. The need for a solid basis in monetary affairs would produce a rapid acceptance of the gold standard in the period that followed.

Japan[edit]

By way of example, and following Germany's decision after the Franco-Prussian War (1870–1871) to extract reparations to facilitate a move to the gold standard, Japan gained the needed reserves after the Sino-Japanese War of 1894–1895. Whether the gold standard provides a government sufficient bona fides when it seeks to borrow abroad is debated. For Japan, moving to gold was considered vital for gaining access to Western capital markets.[5]

The gold exchange standard (1870–1914)[edit]

Towards the end of the 19th century, some of the remaining silver standard countries began to peg their silver coin units to the gold standards of the United Kingdom or the USA. In 1898, British India pegged the silver rupee to the pound sterling at a fixed rate of 1s 4d, while in 1906, the Straits Settlements adopted a gold exchange standard against the pound sterling with the silver Straits dollar being fixed at 2s 4d.

Around the start of the 20th century, the Philippines pegged the silver peso/dollar to the U.S. dollar at 50 cents. A similar pegging at 50 cents occurred at around the same time with the silver peso of Mexico and the silver yen of Japan. When Siam adopted a gold exchange standard in 1908, this left only China and Hong Kong on the silver standard.

When adopting the gold standard, many European nations changed the name of their currency from Daler (Sweden and Denmark) or Gulden (Austria-Hungary) to Crown, since the former names were traditionally associated with silver coins and the latter with gold coins.

Impact of World War I (1914–25)[edit]

Governments faced with the need to fund high levels of expenditure, but with limited sources of tax revenue, suspended convertibility of currency into gold on a number of occasions in the 19th century. The British government suspended convertibility (that is to say, it went off the gold standard) during the Napoleonic wars and the U.S. government during the US Civil War. In both cases, convertibility was resumed after the war.[citation needed] The real test, however, came in the form of World War I, a test which "it failed utterly" according to economist Richard Lipsey.[1]

In order to finance the cost of war, most belligerent countries went off the gold standard during the war, and suffered drastic inflation. Because inflation levels varied between states, when they returned to the standard after the war at price they determined themselves (some, for example, chose to enter at pre-war prices), some countries' goods were undervalued and some overvalued.[1]

Ultimately, the system as it stood could not deal quickly enough with the large deficits and surpluses created in the balance of payments; this has previously been attributed to increasing rigidity of wages (particularly in terms of wage cuts) brought about by the advent of unionized labor, but is now more likely thought of as an inherent fault with the system which came to light under the pressures of war and rapid technological change. In any case, prices had not reached equilibrium by the time of the Great Depression, which served only to kill off the system completely.[1]

For example, Germany had gone off the gold standard in 1914, and could not effectively return to it as that country had lost much of its remaining gold reserves because of reparations. The German central bank issued unbacked marks virtually without limit to buy foreign currency for further reparations and to support workers during the Occupation of the Ruhr, finally leading to hyperinflation in the 1920s.

The gold bullion standard and the decline of the gold standard (1925–31)[edit]

William McKinley ran for president on the basis of the gold standard.

The gold specie standard ended in the United Kingdom and the rest of the British Empire at the outbreak of World War I. Treasury notes replaced the circulation of the gold sovereigns and gold half sovereigns. Legally, the gold specie standard was not repealed. The end of the gold standard was successfully effected by appeals to patriotism when anybody request the Bank of England to redeem his paper money for gold specie. It was only in 1925, when Britain returned to the gold standard in conjunction with Australia and South Africa that the gold specie standard was officially ended.

The British Gold Standard Act 1925 both introduced the gold bullion standard and simultaneously repealed the gold specie standard. The new gold bullion standard did not envisage any return to the circulation of gold specie coins. Instead, the law compelled the authorities to sell gold bullion on demand at a fixed price, but only in the form of bars containing approximately four hundred troy ounces of fine gold.[6] This gold bullion standard lasted until 1931 when speculative attacks on the pound forced Britain off the gold standard.[7] Loans from American and French Central Banks of £50,000,000, were insufficient and exhausted in a matter of weeks.[8]

On September 19, 1931, the United Kingdom left the revised gold standard,[9] forced to suspend the gold bullion standard due to large outflows of gold across the Atlantic Ocean. The British benefited from this departure. They could now use monetary policy to stimulate the economy through the lowering of interest rates. Australia and New Zealand had already been forced off the gold standard by the same pressures connected with the Great Depression which forced British Colonies such as Canada to quickly followed suit with Britain's innovation.

The interwar partially backed gold standard was inherently unstable, because of the conflict between (a) the expansion of sterling and dollar liabilities to foreign central banks and (b) the resulting deterioration in the reserve ratio of the Bank of England, and U.S. Treasury and Federal Reserve Banks.[10] This instability was enhanced by gold flows out of England, with its overvalued pound, to other countries such as France, which was attempting to make Paris a world class financial center, in competition with London and New York.[11]

It was destabilizing speculation, emanating from lack of confidence in authorities' commitment to currency convertibility that ended the interwar gold standard. In May 1931 there was a run on Austria's largest commercial bank, and the bank failed. The run spread to Germany, where the central bank also collapsed. The countries' central banks lost substantial reserves; international financial assistance was too late, and in July 1931 Germany adopted exchange control, followed by Austria in October. These countries were definitively off the gold standard.

The Austrian and German experiences, as well as British budgetary and political difficulties, were among the factors that destroyed confidence in sterling, which occurred in mid-July 1931. Runs on sterling ensued, and the Bank of England lost much of its reserves. Loans from abroad were insufficient, and in any event taken as a sign of weakness. The gold standard was abandoned in September, and the pound quickly and sharply depreciated on the foreign- exchange market, as overvaluation of the pound would imply.[12]

Depression and World War II (1932–46)[edit]

Prolongation of the Great Depression[edit]

Some economic historians, such as American professor Barry Eichengreen, blame the gold standard of the 1920s for prolonging the Great Depression.[13] Adherence to the gold standard prevented the Federal Reserve from expanding the money supply in order to stimulate the economy, fund insolvent banks and fund government deficits which could "prime the pump" for an expansion. Once the US went off the gold standard, it became free to engage in such money creation. The gold standard limited the flexibility of the central banks' monetary policy by limiting their ability to expand the money supply, and thus their ability to lower interest rates. In the US, the Federal Reserve was required by law to have 40% gold backing of its Federal Reserve demand notes, and thus, could not expand the money supply beyond what was allowed by the gold reserves held in their vaults.[14] Others including Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke and Nobel Prize winning economist Milton Friedman place most or all of the blame for the severity of the Great Depression at the feet of the Federal Reserve, mostly due to the deliberate tightening of monetary policy.[15] The US economic contraction in 1937, the last gasp of the Great Depression, is blamed on tightening of monetary policy by the Federal Reserve resulting in a higher cost of capital and weaker securities markets, a reduced net government contribution to income, the undistributed profits tax, and higher labor costs.[16] As a result of the tighter monetary policy, the money supply peaked in March 1937, with a trough in May 1938.[17]

Higher interest rates intensified the deflationary pressure on the dollar and reduced investment in U.S. banks. Commercial banks also converted Federal Reserve Notes to gold in 1931, reducing the Federal Reserve's gold reserves, and forcing a corresponding reduction in the amount of Federal Reserve Notes in circulation.[18] This speculative attack on the dollar created a panic in the U.S. banking system. Fearing imminent devaluation of the dollar, many foreign and domestic depositors withdrew funds from U.S. banks to convert them into gold or other assets.[18] As people pulled money from the banking system due to bank panics, a reverse multiplier effect caused a contraction in the money supply.[19] Additionally the New York Fed had loaned over $150 million (over 240 tons) to European Central Banks to help them out with their difficulties. This transfer of gold out of the US acted to contract the US money supply. These loans became questionable once England, Germany, Austria and other European countries went off the gold standard in 1931 and weakened confidence in the dollar.[20]

The forced contraction of the money supply caused by people removing funds from the banking system during the bank panics resulted in deflation; and even as nominal interest rates dropped, inflation-adjusted real interest rates remained high, rewarding those that held onto money instead of spending it, causing a further slowdown in the economy.[21] Recovery in the United States was slower than in Britain, in part due to Congressional reluctance to abandon the gold standard and float the U.S. currency as Britain had done.[22]

In the early 1930s, the Federal Reserve defended the fixed price of dollars in respect to the gold standard by raising interest rates, trying to increase the demand for dollars. Its commitment and adherence to the gold standard explain why the U.S. did not engage in expansionary monetary policy. To compete in the international economy, the U.S. maintained high interest rates. This helped attract international investors who bought foreign assets with gold.[18]

Congress passed the Gold Reserve Act on 30 January 1934; the measure nationalized all gold by ordering the Federal Reserve banks to turn over their supply to the U.S. Treasury. In return the banks received gold certificates to be used as reserves against deposits and Federal Reserve notes. The act also authorized the president to devalue the gold dollar so that it would have no more than 60 percent of its existing weight. Under this authority the president, on 31 January 1934, changed the value of the dollar from $20.67 to the troy ounce to $35 to the troy ounce, a devaluation of over 40%.

Other factors in the prolongation of the Great Depression include trade wars and the reduction in international trade caused by trade barriers such as Smoot-Hawley Tarriff in the US and the Imperial Preference policies of Great Britain,[23] the failure of central banks to act responsibly,[24] government policies designed to prevent wages from falling, such as the Davis-Bacon Act of 1931, during the deflationary period resulting in production costs dropping slower then sales prices and thereby injuring business profitability [25] and increases in taxes to reduce budget deficits and to support new programs such as Social Security. The US top marginal income tax rate went from 25% to 63% in 1932 and to 79% in 1936[26] while the bottom rate increased over 10 fold from .375% in 1929 to 4% in 1932[27] Successful attacks on partially backed currencies which forced many countries off the gold standard and reduced confidence in the financial system, and a financial system, further damaged by the bank panics of the 1930s were also factors, as was inclement weather such as the drought resulting in the US Dust Bowl.

Milton Friedman stated that "the severity of each of the major contractions — 1920-1, 1929-33 and 1937-8 is directly attributable to acts of commission and omission by the Reserve authorities"[28] He further believes that the US got out of the Great Depression because of the "natural resiliency of the economy and WW2, and not due to any acts of government, which in general were "very destructive" and extended the Great Depression.[29]

Barry Eichengreen believes that the Austrian School view that the Great Depression was the result of a credit bust.[30] Alan Greenspan wrote that the bank failures of the 1930s were sparked by Great Britain dropping the gold standard in 1931. This act "tore asunder" any remaining confidence in the banking system.[31] Financial historian Niall Ferguson writes that what made the Great Depression truly 'great' was the European banking crisis of 1931.[32] According to Fed Chairman M. Eccles, the root cause of the Great Depression was a concentration of wealth resulting in a stagnating or reduction in the standard of living for the poor and middle class. In an attempt to maintain and/or improve their standard of living these classes went into debt, resulting in the credit explosion of the 1920s. Eventually the debt load grew so heavy that it could not be sustained, resulting in the massive defaults and financial panics of the 1930s.[33]

British hesitate to return to gold standard[edit]

John Maynard Keynes, who had argued against such a gold standard, proposed to put the power to print money in the hands of the privately owned Bank of England. Keynes, in warning about the menaces of inflation, said, "By a continuous process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens. By this method, they not only confiscate, but they confiscate arbitrarily; and while the process impoverishes many, it actually enriches some".[34]

Quite possibly because of this, the 1944 Bretton Woods Agreement established the International Monetary Fund and an international monetary system based on convertibility of the various national currencies into a U.S. dollar that was in turn convertible into gold.

Post-war international gold-dollar standard (1946–1971)[edit]

After the Second World War, a system similar to a Gold Standard and sometimes described as a "gold exchange standard" was established by the Bretton Woods Agreements. Under this system, many countries fixed their exchange rates relative to the U.S. dollar. The U.S. promised to fix the price of gold at approximately $35 per ounce. Implicitly, then, all currencies pegged to the dollar also had a fixed value in terms of gold.[1]

Starting under the administration of the French President Charles de Gaulle and continuing until 1970, France reduced its dollar reserves, trading them for gold from the U.S. government, thereby reducing U.S. economic influence abroad. This, along with the fiscal strain of federal expenditures for the Vietnam War and persistent balance of payments deficits, led President Richard Nixon to end the direct convertibility of the dollar to gold on August 15, 1971, resulting in the system's breakdown (the "Nixon Shock").

Theory[edit]

Commodity money is inconvenient to store and transport. Furthermore, it does not allow a government to manipulate or restrict the flow of commerce within its dominion with the same ease that a fiat currency does. As such, commodity money gave way to representative money, and gold and other specie were retained as its backing.

Gold was a common form of money due to its rarity, durability, divisibility, fungibility, and ease of identification,[5] often in conjunction with silver. Silver was typically the main circulating medium, with gold as the metal of monetary reserve.

The gold standard variously specified how the gold backing would be implemented, including the amount of specie per currency unit. The currency itself is just paper and so has no intrinsic value, but is accepted by traders because it can be redeemed any time for the equivalent specie. A U.S. silver certificate, for example, could be redeemed for an actual piece of silver.

Representative money and the gold standard protect citizens from hyperinflation and other abuses of monetary policy, as were seen in some countries during the Great Depression. However, they were not without their problems and critics, and so were partially abandoned via the international adoption of the Bretton Woods System. That system eventually collapsed in 1971, at which time nearly all nations had switched to full fiat money.

According to Keynesian analysis, the earliness with which a country left the gold standard reliably predicted its economic recovery from the great depression. For example, Great Britain and Scandinavia, which left the gold standard in 1931, recovered much earlier than France and Belgium, which remained on gold much longer. Countries such as China, which had a silver standard, almost avoided the depression entirely. The connection between leaving the gold standard as a strong predictor of that country's severity of its depression and the length of time in its recovery has been shown to be consistent for dozens of countries, predominantly in developing countries. This may explain why the experience and length of the depression differed between national economies.[35]

Differing definitions[edit]

A 100%-reserve gold standard, or a full gold standard, exists when a monetary authority holds sufficient gold to convert all of the representative money it has issued into gold at the promised exchange rate. It is sometimes referred to as the gold specie standard to more easily identify it from other forms of the gold standard that have existed at various times. Opponents of a 100%-reserve standard consider a 100%-reserve standard difficult to implement, saying that the quantity of gold in the world is too small to sustain current worldwide economic activity at current gold prices; implementation would entail a many-fold increase in the price of gold.[citation needed] However, proponents of the gold standard have said that any amount of gold can serve as the reserve: "Once a money is established, any stock of money becomes compatible with any amount of employment and real income."[36] According to them the prices of goods and services will adjust to the supply of gold.[37]

In an international gold-standard system (which is necessarily based on an internal gold standard in the countries concerned),[38] gold or a currency that is convertible into gold at a fixed price is used as a means of making international payments. Under such a system, when exchange rates rise above or fall below the fixed mint rate by more than the cost of shipping gold from one country to another, large inflows or outflows occur until the rates return to the official level. International gold standards often limit which entities have the right to redeem currency for gold.

Advantages[edit]

  • Long-term price stability has been described as the great virtue of the gold standard.[39] The gold standard makes it difficult for governments to inflate prices through issuance of paper currency.[40] Under the gold standard, high levels of inflation are rare, and hyperinflation is nearly impossible as the money supply can only grow at the rate that the gold supply increases.[40] Economy-wide price increases caused by ever-increasing amounts of currency chasing a constant supply of goods are rare,[40] as gold supply for monetary use is limited by the available gold that can be minted into coin.[40] High levels of inflation under a gold standard are usually seen only when warfare destroys a large part of the economy, reducing the production of goods, or when a major new source of gold becomes available.[40] In the U.S. one of those periods of warfare was the Civil War, which destroyed the economy of the South,[41] while the California Gold Rush made large amounts of gold available for minting.[42] However, an examination of actual historical data shows that inflation (and deflation) magnitudes were actually far higher under the gold standard.[43]
  • The gold standard provides fixed international exchange rates between those countries that have adopted it, and thus reduces uncertainty in international trade.[40] Historically, imbalances between price levels in different countries would be partly or wholly offset by an automatic balance-of-payment adjustment mechanism called the "price specie flow mechanism."[40] Gold used to pay for imports reduces the money supply of importing nations, causing deflation and a reduction in the general price level for goods and services, making them more competitive, while the importation of gold by net exporters serves to increase the money supply, causes inflation and an increase in the general price level, making them less competitive.[44]
  • A gold standard cannot be used for what some economists call, financial repression.[45] Newly printed money can be used to purchase goods and services, and to discharge debts, at no cost to the printer. This acts as a mechanism to transfer the wealth of society to those that can print money, from everyone else. Financial repression is most successful in liquidating debts when accompanied by a steady dose of inflation, and it can be considered a form of taxation.[46][47] In 1966 Alan Greenspan wrote "Deficit spending is simply a scheme for the confiscation of wealth. Gold stands in the way of this insidious process. It stands as a protector of property rights. If one grasps this, one has no difficulty in understanding the statists' antagonism toward the gold standard."[48] Per John Maynard Keynes "By a continuing process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens".[49] Financial repression negatively affects economic growth.[50] In the US and United Kingdom, from 1945 to 1980 negative real interest rates have cost lenders an estimated 3-4% of GDP per year on average.[51]

Disadvantages[edit]

Gold prices (US$ per ounce) from 1968 to 2010, in nominal US$ and inflation adjusted US$.
  • The unequal distribution of gold as a natural resource makes the gold standard much more advantageous in terms of cost and international economic empowerment for those countries that produce gold.[52] In 2010 the largest producers of gold, in order, are China, followed by Australia, the US, South Africa and Russia.[53] The country with the largest reserves is Australia.[54]
  • The gold standard acts as a limit on economic growth.[55] “As an economy’s productive capacity grows, then so should its money supply. Because a gold standard requires that money be backed in the metal, then the scarcity of the metal constrains the ability of the economy to produce more capital and grow.”[55]
  • Mainstream economists believe that economic recessions can be largely mitigated by increasing money supply during economic downturns.[56] Following a gold standard would mean that the amount of money would be determined by the supply of gold, and hence monetary policy could no longer be used to stabilize the economy in times of economic recession.[57] Such reason is often employed to in part blame the gold standard for the Great Depression, citing that the Federal Reserve couldn't expand credit at a fast enough rate to offset the deflationary forces at work in the market.[58]
  • Although the gold standard has brought long-run price stability, it has also historically been associated with high short-run price volatility.[59][60] It has been argued by, among others, Anna Schwartz, that this kind of instability in short-term price levels can lead to financial instability as lenders and borrowers become uncertain about the value of debt.[61]
  • The total amount of gold that has ever been mined has been estimated at around 142,000 metric tons[62] and arguments have been made that this amount is too small to serve as a monetary base. The value of this amount of gold is over 6 trillion dollars while the monetary base of the US, with a roughly 20% share of the world economy, stands at $2.7 trillion at the end of 2011.[63] Murray Rothbard argues that the amount of gold available is not a bar to a gold standard since the free market will determine the purchasing power of gold money based on its supply.[64]
  • Deflation punishes debtors.[65][66] Real debt burdens therefore rise, causing borrowers to cut spending to service their debts or to default. Lenders become wealthier, but may choose to save some of their additional wealth rather than spending it all.[67] The overall amount of expenditure is therefore likely to fall.[67]
  • Monetary policy would essentially be determined by the rate of gold production.[68] Fluctuations in the amount of gold that is mined could cause inflation if there is an increase, or deflation if there is a decrease.[59][68] Some hold the view that this contributed to the severity and length of the Great Depression as the gold standard forced the central banks to keep monetary policy too tight, creating deflation.[69][70]
  • James Hamilton contended that the gold standard may be susceptible to speculative attacks when a government's financial position appears weak, although others contend that this very threat discourages governments' engaging in risky policy (see Moral Hazard).[70] For example, some believe that the United States was forced to contract the money supply and raise interest rates in September 1931 to defend the dollar after speculators forced Great Britain off the gold standard[70][71][72]
  • If a country wanted to devalue its currency, a gold standard would generally produce sharper changes than the smooth declines seen in fiat currencies, depending on the method of devaluation.[73]
  • Most economists favor a low, positive rate of inflation. Partly this reflects fear of deflationary shocks, but primarily because they believe that central banks still have some role to play in dampening fluctuations in output and unemployment. Central banks can more safely play that role when a positive rate of inflation gives them room to tighten money growth without inducing price declines.[74]
  • It is difficult to manipulate a gold standard to tailor to an economy’s demand for money, providing practical constraints against the measures that central banks might otherwise use to respond to economic crises.[75] The demand for money always equals the supply of money. Creation of new money reduces interest rates and thereby increases demand for new lower cost debt, raising the demand for money.[76]

Advocates of a renewed gold standard[edit]

The return to the gold standard is supported by many followers of the Austrian School of Economics, Objectivists, free-market libertarians[77] and, in the United States, by strict constitutionalists largely because they object to the role of the government in issuing fiat currency through central banks. A significant number of gold-standard advocates also call for a mandated end to fractional-reserve banking.[citation needed]

Few politicians[78] today advocate a return to the gold standard, other than adherents of the Austrian school and some supply-siders. However, some prominent economists have expressed sympathy with a hard-currency basis, and have argued against politically-controlled fiat money, including former U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan (himself a former Objectivist), and macro-economist Robert Barro.[79] Greenspan famously argued the case for returning to a 'pure' gold standard in his 1966 paper "Gold and Economic Freedom", in which he described supporters of fiat currencies as "welfare statists" intending to use monetary policies to finance deficit spending.[80]

Barro argues in favor of adopting some form of "monetary constitution" that will provide stability to monetary policy rather than allowing decisions about monetary policy to be made on the basis of politics. He suggests that what form this constitution takes—for example, a gold standard, some other commodity-based standard, or a fiat currency with fixed rules for determining the quantity of money—is considerably less important.[79] U.S. Congressman Ron Paul has continually argued for the reinstatement of the gold standard, but is no longer a strict advocate, instead supporting a basket of commodities that emerges on the free markets.[81]

For the time being, the global monetary system continues to rely on the U.S. dollar as a reserve currency by which major transactions, such as the price of gold itself, are measured.[82] A host of alternatives has been suggested, including energy-based currencies, and market baskets of currencies or commodities, gold being one of the alternatives.

In 2001, Malaysian Prime Minister Mahathir bin Mohamad proposed a new currency that would be used initially for international trade among Muslim nations. The currency he proposed was called the Islamic gold dinar and it was defined as 4.25 grams of pure (24-carat) gold. Mahathir Mohamad promoted the concept on the basis of its economic merits as a stable unit of account and also as a political symbol to create greater unity between Islamic nations. The purported purpose of this move would be to reduce dependence on the United States dollar as a reserve currency, and to establish a non-debt-backed currency in accord with Islamic law against the charging of interest.[83] However, to date, Mahathir's proposed gold-dinar currency has failed to take hold.

In 2011, the legislature of the state of Utah passed a bill to accept federally issued gold and silver coins as legal tender to pay taxes.[84][85] Similar legislation is under consideration in other US states.

Gold as a reserve today[edit]

The Swiss Franc was based on a 40% legal gold-reserve requirement from 1936, when it ended gold convertibility,[86] until 2000. Gold reserves are held in significant quantity by many nations as a means of defending their currency, and hedging against the U.S. Dollar, which forms the bulk of liquid currency reserves. [87] Both gold coins and gold bars are traded in liquid markets and serve as a private store of wealth.

See also[edit]

International institutions

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b c d e Lipsey, Richard G. (1975). An introduction to positive economics (fourth ed.). Weidenfeld & Nicolson. pp. 683–702. ISBN 0-297-76899-9.
  2. ^ Bordo, Michael D.; Dittmar, Robert D.; Gavin, William T. (June 2003). "Gold, Fiat Money and Price Stability" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Retrieved December 24, 2011. in a world with two capital goods, the one with the lower depreciation rate emerges as commodity money
  3. ^ 610 BC Lydians of Asia Minor invent coinage; shortly afterward it spreads to Greek cities in Asia Minor, then Greek islands, then Greek mainland, then rest of world
  4. ^ Day, John (2007). "A Note on Monetary Mechanisms, East and West". In Angeliki E. Laiou (ed.). The Economic History of Byzantium (Volume 3). Dumbarton Oaks.
  5. ^ a b Metzler, Mark (2006). Lever of Empire: The International Gold Standard and the Crisis of Liberalism in Prewar Japan. Berkeley: University of California Press. p. [1]. ISBN 0-520-24420-6. Cite error: The named reference "ease" was defined multiple times with different content (see the help page).
  6. ^ "Articles: Free the Planet: Gold Standard Act 1925". Free the Planet. 2009-06-10. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  7. ^ "This is a Bill for the temporary Amendment of the Gold Standard Act, 1925, and the Amendment takes the form of suspending Section 1, Subsection (2)". Freetheplanet.net. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  8. ^ "To meet that situation the Bank of England about the beginning of August raised a very large credit, no less than £50,000,000, from the American and French central banks to meet the withdrawals, but within a couple of weeks these resources were practically exhausted". Freetheplanet.net. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  9. ^ Eichengreen, Barry J. (September 15, 2008). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. Princeton University Press. pp. 61–. ISBN 978-0-691-13937-1. Retrieved November 23, 2010.
  10. ^ Encyclopedia. "The gold-exchange standard was inherently unstable, because of the conflict between (a) the expansion of sterling and dollar liabilities to foreign central banks to expand world liquidity, and (b) the resulting deterioration in the reserve ratio of the Bank of England, and U.S. Treasury and Federal Reserve Banks". Eh.net. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  11. ^ Encyclopedia. "there was ongoing tension with France, that resented the sterling-dominated gold- exchange standard and desired to cash in its sterling holding for gold to aid its objective of achieving first-class financial status for Paris". Eh.net. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  12. ^ Encyclopedia. "2 paragraphs are cut and paste material from "Breakdown of the Interwar Gold Standard"". Eh.net. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  13. ^ Eichengreen, Barry (1992) Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939. Preface.
  14. ^ American Economic Association (2000–2011). "The Elasticity of the Federal Reserve Note". JSTOR - the American Economic Review. 26 (4). ITHAKA: 683–690. JSTOR 1807996. Retrieved 10 July 2012.
  15. ^ "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke At the Conference to Honor Milton Friedman". The Federal Reserve Board. November 8, 2002. Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  16. ^ "A Monetary History of the US 1867-1960 Friedman and Schwartz page 543". Scribd.com. 2011-09-09. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  17. ^ A Monetary History of the US 1867-1960 Friedman and Schwartz page 544
  18. ^ a b c "FRB: Speech, Bernanke-Money, Gold, and the Great Depression -March 2, 2004". Federalreserve.gov. 2004-03-02. Retrieved 2010-07-24.
  19. ^ "1931—"The Tragic Year"". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved December 24, 2011. The inflationary attempts of the government from January to October were thus offset by the people's attempts to convert their bank deposits into legal tender" "Hence, the will of the public caused bank reserves to decline by $400 million in the latter half of 1931, and the money supply, as a consequence, fell by over four billion dollars in the same period.
  20. ^ "1931—"The Tragic Year"". Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved December 24, 2011. Throughout the European crisis, the Federal Reserve, particularly the New York Bank, tried its best to aid the European governments and to prop up unsound credit positions. ... The New York Federal Reserve loaned, in 1931, $125 million to the Bank of England, $25 million to the German Reichsbank, and smaller amounts to Hungary and Austria. As a result, much frozen assets were shifted, to become burdens to the United States.
  21. ^ "In the 1930s, the United States was in a situation that satisfied the conditions for a liquidity trap. Over 1929–1933 overnight rates fell to zero, and they remained on the floor through the 1930's."[dead link]
  22. ^ The European Economy between Wars; Feinstein, Temin, and Toniolo
  23. ^ Dominic Sandbrook (2011-12-31). "In August 1932, the British colonies and dominions met in the Canadian capital, Ottawa, and agreed a policy of Imperial Preference, putting high tariffs on goods from outside the Empire". Dailymail.co.uk. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  24. ^ M. Friedman "the severity of each of the major contractions — 1920-1, 1929-33 and 1937-8 is directly attributable to acts of commission and omission by the Reserve authorities".
  25. ^ Robert P. Murphy. "Another major factor is that governments in the 1930s were interfering with wages and prices more so than at any prior point in (peacetime) history". Mises.org. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  26. ^ http://www.cato.org/pubs/tbb/tbb-0303-14.pdf
  27. ^ "per data from Economics Professor Mark J. Perry". Mjperry.blogspot.com. 2008-11-09. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  28. ^ Česky. "This evidence persuades me that at least a third of the price rise during and just after World War I is attributable to the establishment of the [[Federal Reserve System]]... and that the severity of each of the major contractions — 1920-1, 1929-33 and 1937-8 is directly attributable to acts of commission and omission by the Reserve authorities". En.wikiquote.org. Retrieved 2012-07-09. {{cite web}}: URL–wikilink conflict (help)
  29. ^ "Milton Friedman: Roosevelt's policies were very destructive. Roosevelt's policies made the depression longer and worse than it otherwise would have been. What pulled us out of the depression was the natural resilience of the economy + WW2". Rightwingnews.com. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  30. ^ Eichengreen, Barry; Mitchener, Kris (August 2003). "The Great Depression as a Credit Boom Gone Wrong" (PDF). Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  31. ^ Gold and Economic Freedom by Alan Greenspan 1966 "Great Britain fared even worse, and rather than absorb the full consequences of her previous folly, she abandoned the gold standard completely in 1931, tearing asunder what remained of the fabric of confidence and inducing a world-wide series of bank failures."
  32. ^ Farrell, Paul B. (December 13, 2011). "Our decade from hell will get worse in 2012". MarketWatch. Retrieved December 24, 2011. As financial historian Niall Ferguson writes in Newsweek: "Double-Dip Depression ... We forget that the Great Depression was like a soccer match, there were two halves." The 1929 crash kicked off the first half. But what "made the depression truly 'great' ...began with the European banking crisis of 1931." Sound familiar?
  33. ^ Aftershock by Robert B. Reich, published 2010 Chapter 1 Eccles's Insight.
  34. ^ John Maynard Keynes Economic Consequences of the Peace, 1920.
  35. ^ Bernanke, Ben (March 2, 2004), "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke: Money, Gold and the Great Depression", At the H. Parker Willis Lecture in Economic Policy, Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia.
  36. ^ Hoppe, Hans-Herman (1992). Mark Skousen (ed.). Dissent on Keynes, A Critical Appraisal of Economics. pp. 199–223.
  37. ^ "Gold as Money: FAQ". Mises.org. Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved 12 August 2011.
  38. ^ The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edition (2008), Vol.3, S.695
  39. ^ Bordo, Michael D. (2008). "Gold Standard". According to some, the great virtue of the gold standard was that it assured long-term price stability.
  40. ^ a b c d e f g "Advantages of the Gold Standard" (PDF). The Gold Standard: Perspectives in the Austrian School. The Ludwig von Mises Institute. Retrieved 9 January 2011.
  41. ^ Ransom, Roger L. (February 1, 2010). "The Economics of the Civil War". Economic History Association. Retrieved December 24, 2011. the Union also experienced inflation as a result of deficit finance during the war; the consumer price index rose from 100 at the outset of the war to 175 by the end of 1865
  42. ^ Whaples, Robert (February 5, 2010). "California Gold Rush". Economic History Association. Retrieved December 24, 2011. from 1792 until 1847 cumulative U.S. production of gold was only about 37 tons. California's production in 1849 alone exceeded this figure, and annual production from 1848 to 1857 averaged 76 tons. ... Soaring gold output from the California and Australia gold rushes is linked with a 30 percent increase in wholesale prices from 1850 through 1855
  43. ^ http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2012/08/why-the-gold-standard-is-the-worlds-worst-economic-idea-in-2-charts/261552/
  44. ^ "Reform of the International Monetary and Financial System" (PDF). Bank of England. December 2011. Retrieved December 24, 2011. Countries with current account surpluses accumulated gold, while deficit countries saw their gold stocks diminish. This, in turn, contributed to upward pressure on domestic spending and prices in surplus countries and downward pressure on them in deficit countries, thereby leading to a change ... that should, eventually, have reduced imbalances.
  45. ^ "Financial Repression Redux". International Monetary Fund. June 2011. Retrieved December 24, 2011. Financial repression occurs when governments implement policies to channel to themselves funds that in a deregulated market environment would go elsewhere
  46. ^ Reinhart, Carmen M. and Rogoff, Kenneth S., This Time is Different. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2008, p. 143
  47. ^ Government Revenue from Financial Repression Giovannini, Alberto and de Melo, Martha, The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 4 Sep. 1993 (pp. 953-963)
  48. ^ Greenspan, Alan (1966). "Gold and Economic Freedom". Constitution.org. Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  49. ^ "Gold, Peace and Prosperity page 99" (PDF). Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  50. ^ "N. Roubini and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, Financial Repression and Economic Growth "We find that financial repression has negative consequences for growth."". Papers.ssrn.com. 2004-04-23. SSRN 262716. Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  51. ^ "The Liquidation of Government Debt" (PDF). Retrieved December 24, 2011. our estimate of the national liquidation of debt via negative real interest rates amounted on average from 3 to 4 percent of GDP per year.
  52. ^ Goodman, George J.W., Paper Money, 1981, p.165-6
  53. ^ Hill, Liezel (January 13, 2011). "Gold mine output hit record in 2010, more gains likely this year – GFMS". Mining Weekly. Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  54. ^ U.S. Geological Survey (January 2011). "GOLD" (PDF). U.S. Geological Survey, Mineral Commodity Summaries. U.S. Department of the Interior | U.S. Geological Survey. Retrieved 10 July 2012.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link)
  55. ^ a b Mayer, David A. The Everything Economics Book: From theory to practice, your complete guide to understanding economics today (Everything Series) ISBN 978-1-4405-0602-4. 2010. Pgs. 33-34.
  56. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2002). Macroeconomics (5th ed.). Worth. pp. 238–255. ISBN 0-324-17190-0.
  57. ^ Krugman, Paul. "The Gold Bug Variations". Slate.com. Retrieved 2009-02-13.
  58. ^ Timberlake, Richard H. 2005. "Gold Standards and the Real Bills Doctrine in US Monetary Policy". Econ Journal Watch 2(2): 196–233. [2]
  59. ^ a b Bordo, Michael D. (2008). "Gold Standard". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. ISBN 978-0-86597-666-5. OCLC 123350134. Retrieved 2010-08-28.
  60. ^ Michael D. Bordo, Robert Dittmar, and William T. Gavin "Gold, Fiat Money and Price Stability" May 2007 [3]
  61. ^ Bordo, Michael D. (May 2007). "Gold, Fiat Money and Price Stability" (PDF). Working Paper Series. Research Division - Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Retrieved 27 August 2011. {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  62. ^ Butterman, W.C. (2005). Mineral Commodity Profiles—Gold (PDF). Reston, Virginia: United States Geological Survey. OCLC 62034878. Retrieved 2008-11-12. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)[page needed]
  63. ^ Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (27). "St. Louis Adjusted Monetary Base (BASE)". Economic Research - Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Retrieved 10 July 2012. {{cite web}}: Check date values in: |date= and |year= / |date= mismatch (help); Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)
  64. ^ Murray N. Rothbard (Unknown). "Money in a Free Society". What Has Government Done to Our Money?. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. Retrieved 11 July 2012. {{cite web}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  65. ^ Keogh, Bryan (May 13, 2009). "Real Rate Shock Hits CEOs as Borrowing Costs Impede Recovery". Bloomberg. Retrieved December 24, 2011. Deflation hurts borrowers and rewards savers," said Drew Matus, senior economist at Banc of America Securities-Merrill Lynch in New York, in a telephone interview. "If you do borrow right now, and we go through a period of deflation, your cost of borrowing just went through the roof.
  66. ^ Mauldin, John (9 February 2011). Endgame: The End of the Debt SuperCycle and How It Changes Everything. Hoboken, N.J.: John Wiley. ISBN 978-1-118-00457-9. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  67. ^ a b "The greater of two evils". The Economist. May 7, 2009. Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  68. ^ a b DeLong, Brad (1996-08-10). "Why Not the Gold Standard?". Berkeley, California: University of California, Berkeley. Retrieved 2008-09-25.
  69. ^ Warburton, Clark (1966). "The Monetary Disequilibrium Hypothesis". Depression, Inflation, and Monetary Policy: Selected Papers, 1945–1953. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. pp. 25–35. OCLC 736401.
  70. ^ a b c Hamilton, James D. (2005-12-12). "The gold standard and the Great Depression". Econbrowser. Retrieved 2008-11-12. See also Hamilton, James D. (April 1988). "Role of the International Gold Standard in Propagating the Great Depression". Contemporary Economic Policy. 6 (2): 67–89. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7287.1988.tb00286.x. Retrieved 2008-11-12.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link)
  71. ^ Christina D. Romer (20). "Great Depression" (PDF). ELSA. University of California Regents. Retrieved 10 July 2012. {{cite web}}: Check date values in: |date= and |year= / |date= mismatch (help); Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)
  72. ^ "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke". The Federal Reserve Board. March 2, 2004. Retrieved December 24, 2011. "In September 1931, following a period of financial upheaval in Europe that created concerns about British investments on the Continent, speculators attacked the British pound, presenting pounds to the Bank of England and demanding gold in return. ... Unable to continue supporting the pound at its official value, Great Britain was forced to leave the gold standard, ... With the collapse of the pound, speculators turned their attention to the U.S. dollar
  73. ^ McArdle, Megan (2007-09-04). "There's gold in them thar standards!". The Atlantic Monthly. Retrieved 2008-11-12.
  74. ^ Hummel, Jeffrey Rogers. "Death and Taxes, Including Inflation: the Public versus Economists" (January 2007).[4] p.56
  75. ^ Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli; Detragiache, Enrica (April 2005). "Cross-Country Empirical Studies of Systemic Bank Distress: A Survey". National Institute Economic Review. 192 (1): 68–83. doi:10.1177/002795010519200108. ISSN 0027-9501. OCLC 90233776. S2CID 153360324. Retrieved 2008-11-12.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link)
  76. ^ "the quantity of money supplied by the Fed must be equal to the quantity demanded by money holders" (PDF). Retrieved 2012-07-09.
  77. ^ "Time to Think about the Gold Standard? | Cato @ Liberty". Cato-at-liberty.org. 2009-03-12. Retrieved 2010-07-24.
  78. ^ Paul, Ron (1982). The case for gold: a minority report of the U.S. Gold Commission (PDF). Washington, D.C.: Cato Institute. p. 160. ISBN 0-932790-31-3. OCLC 8763972. Retrieved 2008-11-12. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  79. ^ a b Salerno, Joseph T. (1982-09-09). "The Gold Standard: An Analysis of Some Recent Proposals". Cato Policy Analysis. Cato Institute. Retrieved 2009-03-23.
  80. ^ Greenspan, Alan (July 1966). "Gold and Economic Freedom". The Objectivist. 5 (7). Retrieved 2008-10-16.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link)
  81. ^ Channel: CNBC. Show: Squawk Box. Date: 11/13/2009. Interview with Ron Paul
  82. ^ McGregor, Richard (2011-01-16). "Richard McGregor:Hu questions future role of US dollar. Financial Times, January 16, 2011". Financial Times. Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  83. ^ al-'Amraawi, Muhammad (2001-07-01). "Declaration of 'Ulama on the Gold Dinar". Islam i Dag. Retrieved 2008-11-14. {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  84. ^ Clark, Stephen (March 3, 2011). "Utah Considers Return to Gold, Silver Coins". Fox News. Retrieved December 24, 2011.
  85. ^ Spillius, Alex (2011-03-18). "Tea Party legislation reveals anxiety at US direction under Barack Obama". The Daily Telegraph. London.
  86. ^ MacEdo, Jorge Braga de; Eichengreen, Barry J; Reis, Jaime (1996). Currency convertibility: The gold standard and beyond. ISBN 978-0-415-14057-7.
  87. ^ http://www.gfmag.com/tools/global-database/economic-data/11859-international-reserves-by-country.html

Further reading[edit]

External links[edit]

Listen to this page (25 minutes)
Spoken Wikipedia icon
This audio file was created from a revision of this page dated 4 December 2007 (2007-12-04), and does not reflect subsequent edits.