Jump to content

New institutionalism

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Neoinstitutionalism)

Neo institutionalism (also referred to as neo-institutionalist theory or institutionalism) is an approach to the study of institutions that focuses on the constraining and enabling effects of formal and informal rules on the behavior of individuals and groups.[1] New institutionalism traditionally encompasses three major strands: sociological institutionalism, rational choice institutionalism, and historical institutionalism.[2][3] New institutionalism originated in work by sociologist John Meyer published in 1977.[4]

History

[edit]

The study of institutions and their interactions has been a focus of academic research for many years. In the late 19th and early 20th century, social theorists began to systematize this body of literature. One of the most prominent examples of this was the work of German economist and social theorist Max Weber; Weber focused on the organizational structure (i.e. bureaucracy) within society, and the institutionalization created by means of the iron cage which organizational bureaucracies create. In Britain and the United States, the study of political institutions dominated political science until the 1950s. This approach, sometimes called 'old' institutionalism, focused on analyzing the formal institutions of government and the state in comparative perspective. It was followed by a behavioral revolution which brought new perspectives to analyzing politics, such as positivism, rational choice theory, and behavioralism, and the narrow focus on institutions was discarded as the focus moved to analyzing individuals rather than the institutions which surrounded them.[5] New Institutionalism was a reaction to the behavioral revolution.[5][6]

Institutionalism experienced a significant revival in 1977 with two influential papers by John W. Meyer and Brian Rowan on one hand and Lynn Zucker on the other.[7][8] The revised formulation of institutionalism proposed in this paper prompted a significant shift in the way institutional analysis was conducted. Research that followed became known as "new" institutionalism, a concept that is generally referred to as "neo-institutionalism" in academic literature. Another significant reformulation occurred with Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell's paper on isomorphism.[9][8] The three papers had in common that they explained the practices of organizations not in terms of efficacy and efficiency, but in terms of legitimacy. The functions of an organization did not necessarily reflect rational or optimal ends, but were instead myths, ceremonies and scripts that had a veneer of rationality.[8]

The following decade saw an explosion of literature on the topic across many disciplines, including those outside of the social sciences. Examples of the body of work in the decade which followed can be found in DiMaggio and Powell's 1991 anthology in the field of sociology;[8] in economics, the Nobel Prize-winning work of Douglass North is a noted example.

More-recent work has begun to emphasize multiple competing logics,[10][11] focusing on the more-heterogeneous sources of diversity within fields[11] and the institutional embeddedness of technical considerations.[12][13] The concept of logic generally refers to broader cultural beliefs and rules that structure cognition and guide decision-making in a field. At the organization level, logic can focus the attention of key decision-makers on a delimited set of issues and solutions,[14] leading to logic-consistent decisions that reinforce extant organizational identities and strategies.[15] In line with the new institutionalism, social rule system theory stresses that particular institutions and their organizational instantiations are deeply embedded in cultural, social, and political environments and that particular structures and practices are often reflections of as well as responses to rules, laws, conventions, paradigms built into the wider environment.[16]

Old institutionalism

[edit]

Kathleen Thelen and Sven Steinmo contrast New Institutionalism with "Old Institutionalism", which was overwhelmingly focused on detailed narratives of institutions, with little focus on comparative analyses. Thus, the Old Institutionalism was unhelpful for comparative research and explanatory theory. This "Old Institutionalism" began to be undermined when scholars increasingly highlighted how the formal rules and administrative structures of institutions were not accurately describing the behavior of actors and policy outcomes.[17]

Definition of institution

[edit]

There is no agreed upon definition of institution in new institutionalist scholarship.[8] Mats Alvesson and Andre Spicer wrote in 2018 that it had become "difficult to agree what an institution is not – because institutions have become everything... When the term institution is defined, it is done so in broad and vague ways."[8]

Diversity of scholarship

[edit]

Numerous scholarly approaches have been described as being part of New institutionalism.[2][5][18]

Sociological institutionalism

[edit]

Sociological institutionalism is a form of new institutionalism that concerns "the way in which institutions create meaning for individuals, providing important theoretical building blocks for normative institutionalism within political science".[19] Some sociological institutionalists argue that institutions have developed to become similar (showing an isomorphism) across organizations even though they evolved in different ways.[20][7] Institutions are therefore seen as important in cementing and propagating cultural norms.[21] Sociological institutionalists also emphasize how the functions and structures of organizations do not necessarily reflect functional purposes, but rather ceremonies and rituals.[3][7] Actors comply with institutional rules and norms because other types of behavior are inconceivable; actors follow routines because they take a for-granted quality.[22][23]

Normative institutionalism is a sociological interpretation of institutions and holds that a "logic of appropriateness" guides the behavior of actors within an institution. It predicts that the norms and formal rules of institutions will shape the actions of those acting within them. According to James March,[24] the logic of appropriateness means that actions are "matched to situations by means of rules organized into identities." Thus normative institutionalism views that much of the behavior of institutional actors is based on the recognized situation that the actors encounter, the identity of the actors in the situation, and the analysis by the actor of the rules that generally govern behavior for that actor in that particular situation.

New institutional economics

[edit]

New institutional economics (NIE) is an economic perspective that attempts to extend economics by focusing on the institutions (that is to say the social and legal norms and rules) that underlie economic activity and with analysis beyond earlier institutional economics and neoclassical economics. It can be seen as a broadening step to include aspects excluded in neoclassical economics. It rediscovers aspects of classical political economy. Major scholars associated with the subject include Masahiko Aoki, Armen Alchian, Harold Demsetz,[25][26] Steven N. S. Cheung,[27][28] Avner Greif, Yoram Barzel, Claude Ménard (economist), Daron Acemoglu, and four Nobel laureates—Ronald Coase,[29][30] Douglass North,[31][32] Elinor Ostrom,[33] and Oliver Williamson.[34][35][36] A convergence of such researchers resulted in founding the Society for Institutional & Organizational Economics (formerly the International Society for New Institutional Economics) in 1997.

Rational choice institutionalism

[edit]

Rational choice institutionalism is a theoretical approach to the study of institutions arguing that actors use institutions to maximize their utility.[37][38] Institutions are understood to be exogenously given constraints ("rules of the game") on rational individual behavior. It employs analytical tools borrowed from neo-classical economics to explain how institutions are created, the behaviour of political actors within it, and the outcome of strategic interaction. Rational choice institutionalism draws heavily from rational choice theory but is not identical to it. Proponents argue that political actors' rational choices are constrained (called "bounded rationality"). These bounds are accepted as individuals realize their goals can be best achieved through institutions. In other words, institutions are systems of rules and inducements to behavior in which individuals attempt to maximize their own benefit.

According to Erik Voeten, rational choice scholarship on institutions can be divided between (1) rational functionalism and (2) Distributive rationalism.[38] The former sees organizations as functional optimal solutions to collective problems, whereas the latter sees organizations as an outcome of actors' individual and collective goals.[38] Since individual and collective goals may conflict, the latter version of RCI accepts that suboptimal institutions are likely.[39]

Historical institutionalism

[edit]

Emphasizes how timing, sequences and path dependence affect institutions, and shape social, political, economic behavior and change.[40][41] Unlike functionalist theories and some rational choice approaches, historical institutionalism tends to emphasize that many outcomes are possible, small events and flukes can have large consequences, actions are hard to reverse once they take place, and that outcomes may be inefficient. A critical juncture may set in motion events that are hard to reverse, because of issues related to path dependency.[42][43][44][45] Historical institutionalists tend to focus on history (longer temporal horizons) to understand why specific events happen.[40][46]

Discursive institutionalism

[edit]

Proponents of discursive institutionalism, such as Vivien Schmidt, emphasize how ideas and discourses affect institutional stability and change.[47][48]

Constructivist institutionalism

[edit]

Constructivist institutionalists[49] assert that political, social, or policy discourses can perform communicative functions: actors publicly expressing ideas can lead to social change, or coordinating functions. Thus ideas and meaning provide a mechanism for multiple actors to achieve consensus on norms and values and thus create social change.[50] This is increasingly moving beyond political science and into international relations theory and foreign policy analysis.[51][52]

Feminist institutionalism is a new institutionalist approach which looks at "how gender norms operate within institutions and how institutional processes construct and maintain gender power dynamics".[19][53]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ DiMaggio, Paul (1998). "The New Institutionalisms : Avenues of Collaboration". Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE). 154 (4): 696–705. ISSN 0932-4569. JSTOR 40752104.
  2. ^ a b Hall, Peter A.; Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1996). "Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms*". Political Studies. 44 (5): 936–957. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9248.1996.tb00343.x. hdl:11858/00-001M-0000-0012-59C1-5. ISSN 1467-9248. S2CID 3133316.
  3. ^ a b Farrell, Henry (2018), Glückler, Johannes; Suddaby, Roy; Lenz, Regina (eds.), "The Shared Challenges of Institutional Theories: Rational Choice, Historical Institutionalism, and Sociological Institutionalism", Knowledge and Institutions, Knowledge and Space, vol. 13, Springer, pp. 23–44, doi:10.1007/978-3-319-75328-7_2, ISBN 978-3-319-75328-7, S2CID 149806588
  4. ^ Powell, Walter W.; DiMaggio, Paul J. (1991). The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. University of Chicago Press. doi:10.7208/chicago/9780226185941.001.0001. ISBN 978-0-226-67709-5.
  5. ^ a b c Adcock, Robert Bevir, Mark Stimson, Shannon C. (2007). Modern political science : Anglo-American exchanges since 1880. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-12873-3. OCLC 475415787.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  6. ^ Immergut, Ellen M. (1998). "The Theoretical Core of the New Institutionalism". Politics & Society. 26 (1): 5–34. doi:10.1177/0032329298026001002. ISSN 0032-3292. S2CID 143375959.
  7. ^ a b c Meyer & Rowan 1977.
  8. ^ a b c d e f Alvesson, Mats; Spicer, André (2019). "Neo-Institutional Theory and Organization Studies: A Mid-Life Crisis?". Organization Studies. 40 (2): 199–218. doi:10.1177/0170840618772610. ISSN 0170-8406. S2CID 150260582.
  9. ^ DiMaggio & Powell 1983, pp. 147–60.
  10. ^ Friedland & Alford 1991.
  11. ^ a b Lounsbury 2001.
  12. ^ Scott et al. 2000.
  13. ^ Thornton 2004.
  14. ^ Ocasio 1997.
  15. ^ Thornton 2002.
  16. ^ Powell 2007.
  17. ^ "Structuring politics historical institutionalism comparative analysis". Cambridge University Press. 1992. pp. 3–4. Retrieved 2020-02-29.
  18. ^ Ansell, Christopher (2021), Riddervold, Marianne; Trondal, Jarle; Newsome, Akasemi (eds.), "Institutionalism", The Palgrave Handbook of EU Crises, Palgrave Studies in European Union Politics, Springer, pp. 135–152, doi:10.1007/978-3-030-51791-5_7, ISBN 978-3-030-51791-5, S2CID 242915266
  19. ^ a b Lowndes, Vivien (2010), "The Institutional Approach", in Marsh, D.; Stoker, G. (eds.), Theories and Methods in Political Science, Basingstoke: Palgrave, p. 65
  20. ^ DiMaggio & Powell 1991.
  21. ^ Finnemore, Martha (1996). National Interests in International Society. Cornell University Press. p. 3. JSTOR 10.7591/j.ctt1rv61rh.
  22. ^ Scott, Richard W. (2014). Institutions and organizations : ideas, interests and identities. Sage. ISBN 978-1-45224222-4. OCLC 945411429.
  23. ^ Schmidt, V.A. (2010), Taking ideas and discourse seriously: explaining change through discursive institutionalism as the fourth 'new institutionalism'.
  24. ^ March, James G. (1994), Primer on Decision Making: How Decisions Happen, Free Press, pp. 57–58.
  25. ^ Harold Demsetz (1967). "Toward a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review, 57(2), pp. 347–359[dead link].
  26. ^ Harold Demsetz (1969) "Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint," Journal of Law and Economics, 12(1), pp. [1][dead link].
  27. ^ Steven N. S. Cheung (1970). "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), pp. 49–70.
  28. ^ S. N. S. Cheung (1973). "The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation," Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), pp. 11–33.
  29. ^ Ronald Coase (1998). "The New Institutional Economics," American Economic Review, 88(2), pp. 72–74.
  30. ^ R. H. Coase (1991). "The Institutional Structure of Production," Nobel Prize Lecture PDF, reprinted in 1992, American Economic Review, 82(4), pp. 713–719.
  31. ^ Douglass C. North (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press.
  32. ^ Douglass C. North (1995). "The New Institutional Economics and Third World Development," in The New Institutional Economics and Third World Development, J. Harriss, J. Hunter, and C. M. Lewis, ed., pp. 17–26.
  33. ^ Elinor Ostrom (2005). "Doing Institutional Analysis: Digging Deeper than Markets and Hierarchies," Handbook of New Institutional Economics, C. Ménard and M. Shirley, eds. Handbook of New Institutional Economics, pp. 819–848. Springer.
  34. ^ Oliver E. Williamson (2000). "The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead," Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), pp. 595–613 Archived May 11, 2011, at the Wayback Machine (press +).Dzionek-Kozłowska, Joanna; Matera, Rafał (October 2015). "New Institutional Economics' Perspective on Wealth and Poverty of Nations. Concise Review and General Remarks on Acemoglu and Robinson's Concept". Annals of the Alexandru Ioan Cuza University – Economics. 62 (1): 11–18. doi:10.1515/aicue-2015-0032.
  35. ^ Keefer, Philip; Knack, Stephen (2005). "Social capital, social norms and the New Institutional Economics". Handbook of New Institutional Economics. pp. 700–725.
  36. ^ "Introductory Reading List: New Institutional Economics". Ronald Coase Institute.
  37. ^ Knight, Jack; Sened, Itai, eds. (1996). Explaining Social Institutions. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. pp. 95–120. doi:10.3998/mpub.14827. ISBN 978-0-472-10588-5.
  38. ^ a b c Voeten, Erik (2019). "Making Sense of the Design of International Institutions". Annual Review of Political Science. 22 (1): 147–163. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-041916-021108. ISSN 1094-2939.
  39. ^ Koremenos, Barbara; Lipson, Charles; Snidal, Duncan (2001). "The Rational Design of International Institutions". International Organization. 55 (4): 761–799. doi:10.1162/002081801317193592. ISSN 0020-8183. JSTOR 3078615. S2CID 41593236.
  40. ^ a b Voeten, Erik (2019). "Making Sense of the Design of International Institutions". Annual Review of Political Science. 22 (1): 147–163. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-041916-021108. ISSN 1094-2939.
  41. ^ Farrell, Henry; Newman, Abraham L. (2010). "Making global markets: Historical institutionalism in international political economy". Review of International Political Economy. 17 (4): 609–638. doi:10.1080/09692291003723672. ISSN 0969-2290. S2CID 153647117.
  42. ^ Pierson, Paul (2000). "Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics". American Political Science Review. 94 (2): 251–267. doi:10.2307/2586011. hdl:1814/23648. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 2586011. S2CID 154860619.
  43. ^ Steinmo, S; Thelen, K; Longstreth, F, eds. (1992), Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis, New York: Cambridge University Press.
  44. ^ Capoccia, Giovanni; Kelemen, R. Daniel (2007). "The Study of Critical Junctures: Theory, Narrative, and Counterfactuals in Historical Institutionalism". World Politics. 59 (3): 341–369. doi:10.1017/S0043887100020852. ISSN 1086-3338.
  45. ^ Thelen, Kathleen; Conran, James (2016). Fioretos, Orfeo; Falleti, Tulia G.; Sheingate, Adam (eds.). Institutional Change. Vol. 1. Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199662814.013.3. ISBN 978-0-19-966281-4.
  46. ^ Wood, Geoffrey T.; Allen, Matthew M C (2020). "Comparing Capitalisms: Debates, Controversies and Future Directions". Sociology. 54 (3): 482–500. doi:10.1177/0038038519895937. hdl:10072/393898.
  47. ^ Schmidt, Vivien A. (2008). "Discursive Institutionalism: The Explanatory Power of Ideas and Discourse". Annual Review of Political Science. 11 (1): 303–326. doi:10.1146/annurev.polisci.11.060606.135342. ISSN 1094-2939.
  48. ^ Schmidt, Vivien A. (2010). "Taking ideas and discourse seriously: explaining change through discursive institutionalism as the fourth 'new institutionalism'". European Political Science Review. 2 (1): 1–25. doi:10.1017/S175577390999021X. ISSN 1755-7747. S2CID 146179398.
  49. ^ Hay, Colin (2006). "Constructivist institutionalism". In Rhodes, R.A.W.; Binder, Sarah A.; Rockman, Bert A. (eds.). The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 56–74. ISBN 978-0-19-954846-0.
  50. ^ Dodds, Anneliese (2013), Comparative Public Policy, Palgrave MacMillan.
  51. ^ Hassan, Oz (10 Sep 2012), Constructing America's freedom agenda for the Middle East, Studies in US Foreign Policy, Routledge, ISBN 978-0-41560310-2.
  52. ^ Hassan, Oz (2010-06-14), "Constructing Crises, (in)securitising terror: the punctuated evolution of EU counter terrorism policy", European Security, 19 (3: European ‘security’ governance), Taylor & Francis: 445–66, doi:10.1080/09662839.2010.526935, S2CID 153658871.
  53. ^ Grahn, Michal (December 2023). "Gendered Institutions and Where to Find Them: A Critical Realist Approach". Politics and Gender: 1–25. doi:10.1017/S1743923X23000624.

Bibliography and further reading

[edit]